Ireland; Past, Present and Future |
by William T. Thornton First published in A Plea for Peasant Proprietors, John Murray, 1848 |
Irish Famine
Links Irish Famine Timeline The Economic Writings of William Thornton Return to Documentation Page Return to Main Page Mail the Site |
Ireland, even more commonly, and with more confidence than France, is appealed to as testifying strongly against small farms and small properties. The 'cottage system,' it is said, has there been tried on a very extensive scale, and has utterly and lamentably failed. Five-sixths of all the farms in the island are less than fifteen acres in extent, and nearly one-half are less than five acres; yet in no part of Europe is agriculture more defective, nor the peasantry more idle and thoughtless, or so miserable and ill-disposed. What reply can be made to a statement, the truth of which is too notorious to be disputed? Simply, that to Irish farms are wanting certain conditions, without which no farms, whether small or great, nor their occupiers, can be expected to flourish. There are no bounds to the tenant's liabilities, and no security against his ejection. That Irish holdings should have been supposed capable of furnishing any argument against peasant properties, is only one among many examples of the profound ignorance which prevails respecting Irish affairs. Ireland is one of the few countries in which there neither are, nor ever were, peasant properties. From the earliest appropriation of the soil, down to the present day, estates have always been of considerable size, and though these estates are now cut up into many small holdings, the actual occupiers of the soil, far from being landowners, are not even lease-holders, but are rackrented tenants at will. In this single phrase may be found a complete explanation of all the evils of their condition, and all the defects of their character. They are indolent, because they have no inducement to work after they have obtained from their labour wherewithal to pay their rent, and to save themselves from starvation. Whatever additional produce they might raise, would only subject them to further exactions. They are careless of the future, because they cannot, by taking thought, improve the gloomy prospects of the morrow; they are reduced to the verge of destitution, because they are permitted to retain no more of the fruits of their labour than will barely suffice for their subsistence; and they set at naught all other laws, divine or human, partly in obedience to the first law of nature, that of self-preservation, and partly because familiarity with misery has rendered them desperate. |
Before we proceed
further, it
may be well to inquire how it is that Irish cottars are unable to make
better bargains with their landlords. In other countries, in which the
property of the soil is not vested in the peasantry, the latter
nevertheless obtain possession of it without submitting to terms
altogether unreasonable. Leases may not perhaps be granted to them, but
they do not suffer the landlord to fix his own rent. They will not
consent to pay more than the land is worth, as a means of employing
their capital and labour. But in Ireland they do not venture to reject
any demands, however outrageous. Whatever rent may be asked, they
readily agree to pay, perfectly heedless whether they shall be able to
fulfil engagements which the necessities of their situation leave them
no choice but to undertake. In a country in which farms are in general
too small to afford employment for hired labour, a peasant has scarcely
a chance of being able to gain a livelihood, unless he obtain
possession of land; and in Ireland the competitors for land are so
numerous, that the price paid for the use of it has reached a degree of
exorbitancy unheard of elsewhere. Such keen competition clearly shows
that population is excessive; that is to say, that the labouring class
is too numerous in proportion to the amount of employment for it; but
it would be a mistake to regard this redundancy of population as a
consequence of the prevalence of small farms. The progress of
population has, indeed, been extraordinarily rapid since the period
when nearly the whole territory was given up to pasturage, and since
the immense grazing farms, by which it was formerly occupied, have been
brought under tillage, and divided amongst more than half a million of
cottage holdings. But population, in becoming more dense, has not,
perhaps, become much more excessive. Ireland was certainly never before
so populous as at present; that is to say, it never before contained so
great a number of inhabitants, but it has long, perhaps, been nearly as
much overpeopled; that is to say, the number of inhabitants has long
been nearly as much disproportioned to the means of subsistence. The
prodigious strides which population has made of late years, have made
the destitution of the poor more obvious than before, but it is
doubtful whether they have rendered it much more severe. The mass of
the people has always been subjected to such extreme privations, that
although the number of sufferers is now far greater, the sufferings of
individuals have not been much aggravated. A very hasty retrospect may
serve to discover the grounds for this opinion.
From the earliest times Ireland has been noted for the excellence of its pastures. Its level surface, overspread with the most luxuriant herbage, presented a wide field over which the cattle of the first settlers might freely range and multiply at an exceedingly rapid rate. Their owners became proportionably wealthy, but the possession of great wealth by individuals implies a corresponding disparity of ranks in the community. The authority of the leader of a tribe may have depended on his personal character or on accidental circumstances, but whatever may have been the political position of the chief with respect to his fellow-herdsmen, the latter, no doubt, exercised almost unlimited power over their servants and dependents. It is, indeed, a recorded fact, that these retainers did, after a while, degenerate into absolute bondsmen, who were attached to the manor on which they dwelt, and, under the name of 'betages,' were as completely at the disposal of their lords as the serfs of Continental Europe. The pastural occupation of the primitive Irish was not laid aside as soon as they had divided their new country amongst them, and had stationed themselves on particular spots, but continued to be practised by their descendants for many generations. The principal obstacle to change was, probably, at first, the nature of the climate, which, Mela says, was as unsuitable for grain as it was favourable to the growth of grass[1]; and this was, perhaps, the sole reason why, so late as the twelfth century, the people could still be represented as despising husbandry, and as not having laid aside their ancient pastoral mode of life.[2] When greater intercourse sprang up between them and more civilised nations, they would have been taught the advantage of cultivating the soil; but, unfortunately, in the long period of anarchy which succeeded to the conquest by Henry the Second, the incessant warfare between the English colonists and the natives acted as an effectual bar to agriculture, for both parties thought it wiser to keep their property in the shape of flocks and herds, which could easily be removed to a place of refuge, than in corn stacks or standing crops, which must have been left to the mercy of a successful invader. Cattle thus continued to be the principal produce of the country, so much so, indeed, that they were often used as a medium of exchange, and that, even in the beginning of the sixteenth century, the Book of Ballymote, is said to have been purchased for 140 milch cows.[3] More than a hundred years later, we find the poet Spenser lamenting that 'all men fell to pasturage and none to husbandry,' and recommending that an ordinance should be made to compel every one who kept twenty kine to keep one plough going likewise. [4] It is not likely that agriculture made much progress during the reigns of Elizabeth and of the first two Stuarts, and during the Protectorate, a period marked by the rebellion of the Earls of Tyrone and Tyrconnel, the massacre of the Protestants at the instigation of Roger Moore, the equally bloody invasion of Cromwell and the confiscation of five-sixths of the island; and, if it did, it must have been thrown back as much as ever after the Revolution of 1688, when a twelfth of the land again changed masters; and in the reign of Queen Anne, when a series of penal acts was directed against the Roman Catholics. These atrocious laws, amongst other monstrous provisions, forbade papists to purchase lands, or to hold them by lease for more than thirty-one years, or to derive from leasehold property a profit greater than one-third of the rent. The great majority of the people being Roman Catholics, were thus, in effect, restrained from the practice of agriculture, and the proprietors of estates had really no option but to let them to the few capitalists who could legally compete for them, and who could not, of course, properly superintend the management of the immense tracts which fell into their hands, except by keeping them almost entirely under grass. So general and so prolonged was the neglect of tillage, that, in the year 1727, a law was made to compel every occupier of 100 acres to cultivate at least five acres; but the injunction seems to have been little regarded, and, until about forty years later, little additional land was brought under the plough. From the earliest times then, until late in the last century, Ireland was almost entirely a grazing country. Now it is true that in pastoral communities which have little commercial intercourse with more civilised nations, every class of persons is commonly sufficiently supplied with the necessaries of life. In such circumstances, a rich herdsman has literally no means of getting rid of his superfluous wealth, except by maintaining a large retinue of servants, and he is naturally liberal enough of the milk, cheese, flesh, hides, and wool, which would be wasted if he did not give them away. But Ireland, from a very remote period, has carried on a considerable export trade, and the owners of the soil have always possessed in foreign countries a market for their surplus produce. It was therefore the interest of the primitive Irish herdsmen to restrain the consumption of their servants, and to confine it within the narrowest possible bounds. When the servants became serfs, they were not, according to the custom in more agricultural countries, provided with portions of land to cultivate for their own support; for the estates of their lords, however extensive, could scarcely be too extensive for pasturage. They lived on such fare as their masters chose to provide, went half-naked, and slept under trees, or the scarcely better shelter of branches cemented together with mud. When they became enfranchised, they gained nothing but personal freedom. Their condition in most other respects remained unchanged. Froissart describes them as living in forests in huts made of boughs, like 'wild beasts'.[5] There was so little demand for labour, that most were still glad to serve for a bare subsistence, and the few who were permitted to be tenants of land, obtained little more from their farms. 'Irish landlords,' says Spenser, 'do not use to set out their lands in farm, or for terms of years, but only from year to year, and some during pleasure; neither indeed will the Irish husbandman otherwise take his land than so long as he lists himself. The reason hereof is, that the landlords used most shamefully to rack their tenants, laying upon them coigns and livery at pleasure, and exacting of them besides his convenants what we pleaseth.' Spenser goes on to speak of the farmhouses, which he calls 'rather swine-styes than houses;' and of the farmer's 'beastly manner of life, and savage condition, lying and living together with his beasts in one house, in one room, in one bed, that is clean straw or rather a foul dunghill.'[6] Matters were not at all mended in 1672, when Sir William Petty made his survey, and estimated that out of 200,000 houses then existing in Ireland, 100,000 were 'wretched, nasty cabins, without chimney, window, or door-shut, even worse than those of the savage Americans.' From these premises it may be inferred that the present misery of the Irish peasantry is of no recent origin, but has been from time immemorial an heirloom in the race. The number of labourers has always been greatly in excess of the demand for labour, and the remuneration of labour has consequently never been much more than sufficient to procure the merest sustenance. This was as much the case when Ireland was one vast grazing farm, and contained few inhabitants beside cattle and their attendants, as now, that the face of the country is cut up into potato gardens, and dotted with cabins, each containing a separate family. The inhabitants have always been as numerous as the country in its actual circumstances could support, and population has only advance in proportion as the limits set to it have been widened. How much soever population may have varied in amount at different periods, it has always been nearly equally in excess of the means of subsistence; and the multiplication of the people, much as it has increased the mass of misery, has not perhaps sensibly aggravated the misery of individuals. The chief difference is that, whereas people were once starving on a short allowance of meat, they are now starving on a short allowance of potatoes. Abundance of the former they never knew, nor of the latter, except during one short period. This brief interval of comparative plenty commenced soon after the middle of the last century, when the increase of tillage increased the demand for farm servants; but the increase was too gradual to produce any material or permanent effect. In the year 1762, the Irish parliament granted high bounties on the inland carriage of grain, and in 1783 and 1784 granted further bounties on its exportation, and prohibited its importation from abroad; and the rise of price which took place in consequence was further promoted by the demand for foreign corn in Great Britain after the commencement of the war with France, and by the abolition in 1806 of all restrictions on the corn trade between this country and Ireland. Inducements were thus given to landholders to substitute tillage for pasturage, and as the tracts held by single graziers were in general much too extensive to be cultivated by the actual tenants, they were divided into farms of more convenient size, and let to such persons as were willing to undertake them. There was not, however, capital enough in the island to meet the requirements of this revolution in husbandry, and most of the new race of farmers were so poor that they could not pay their labourers in any other way than by assigning to them pieces of ground to build cabins upon, and to cultivate for their own subsistence. Together with the farmers, therefore, a considerable body of cottars sprung up, and in this manner the bulk of the peasantry were converted into occupiers of land; but the conversion was effected much less suddenly than is commonly supposed. Although the inland carriage bounty caused a good deal of pasture to be broken up in a few counties, yet, after it had been several years in operation, the proportion of tillage to pasturage over the whole island was still not more than one to ten; and it is certain that the acts of 1783 and 1784 caused only an inconsiderable tract to be brought under the plough. The increase in the exportation of grain, which may be regarded as an exact measure of the increase of cultivation consequent upon those Acts, shows that the latter was inconsiderable. The quantity of corn exported from It is a conclusive proof that
the occupation of land by the
Irish peasantry does not of itself contribute to their misery, that it
is
precisely where the distribution of land amongst them is most general
that
population is least redundant, and the condition of the people most
tolerable.
In Ulster, the number of farms not exceeding five acres in extent, and
the
proportion of inhabitants occupying land, are greater than in any one
of the
other three provinces; yet in Ulster, the competition for land is less
keen
than in the rest of Ireland, and in Ulster only is the English tourist
occasionally reminded
of the happiest parts of his
own country, by the comparative neatness of the white-washed cottages,
and by
the appearance of the comparatively well-dressed and well-fed inmates.
It is
true that Not only, however, are not
small farms the cause of Irish
misery; not only is their preservation quite compatible with the
improvement of
Ireland; their continuance (though on a different tenure) and a
considerable
increase to their number, are perhaps the only means by which the
manifold
disorders of that country can be radically cured. Whatever may have
been the
original source of the wretchedness of the Irish people, its proximate
cause is
evidently a deficiency of employment; the supply of labour so greatly
exceeds
the demand, that multitudes have not adequate means of gaining a
livelihood.
This being the nature of their present distress, no scheme for its
relief can
have complete success which does not furnish them with adequate
occupation, and
it may not be difficult to show that for the agrarian population of
Ireland,
adequate occupation cannot be afforded except on small farms. This will
appear
from a hasty examination of the various schemes proposed. By a large
class of
reasoners, the deficiency of employment is held to be a necessary
consequence
of deficiency of capital, and to be incapable of being supplied except
by the
introduction of additional capital; and as capital will not enter a
country in
which life and property are unprotected, the first step towards
improvement is
declared to be the repression of that spirit of outrage which makes
Ireland the
terror of all who have anything to lose. For this
purpose,
either coercion or conciliation may be tried. But four or five millions
of
famishing desperadoes must be almost exterminated before they can be
dragooned
into loyalty. If force only is to be used, force must create a solitude
in
order to establish peace. Still less can be expected from conciliation,
if by
that term be understood merely the redress of political grievances.
Most of
these causes of complaint have already been removed, without removing
anything
of that bitterness of feeling which they were supposed to have
engendered, and
the redress of the monster grievance which remains, however desirable
on other
accounts, would assuredly not have a much more soothing effect. Should
the
church of the majority be at once reinstated in her ancient position,
and again
endowed with the wealth of which she has been plundered, her clergy
would be
almost the only gainers. The mass of the people would remain as
destitute as
ever, and would have as little reason to submit quietly to their dismal
lot.
The priests, indeed, when in the receipt of liberal stipends, and when
no
longer dependent on voluntary contributions, would have no motives for
affecting to sympathise with the evil passions of their hearers, and
would
rather exert themselves for the maintenance of order. Their influence
has,
however, been exceedingly overrated. With a few disgraceful exceptions,
the
Roman Catholic clergy are not accused, even by their most virulent
calumniators,
of openly countenancing violence. Many have used their utmost efforts
to allay
the evil passions of the people, and almost all are so far mindful of
their
sacred obligations as to remain at least quiescent: if they do not
labour very
earnestly to prevent crime, they do not directly encourage it. In
truth, such
encouragement would be superfluous. Where the materials for spontaneous
combustion exist in such abundance, no torch is needed to kindle them.
The
flames burst forth as freely without any extraneous aid. The outrages
by which
life and property are endangered in But it may be urged, that
although private speculators are
unwilling to venture their money in such a country as There remains no resource but
that of small farms. So far as |
Cultivated Area in Statute Acres:
13,838,782 Number of Families chiefly employed in Agriculture: 974,188 Total Number of Persons holding land: 935,448 Number holding not more than one Acre: 135,314 Number holding between 1 and 2 Acres: 50,355 Number holding between 2 and 3 Acres: 35,951 Number holding between 3 and 4 Acres: 45,363 Number holding between 4 and 5 Acres: 50,281 Number holding between 6 and 7 Acres: 36,630 Number holding between 7 and 8 Acres: 31,610 Number holding between 8 and 9 Acres: 41,596 Number holding between 9 and 10 Acres: 35,408 Number holding between 10 and 20 Acres: 187,582 Number holding between 20 and 50 Acres: 141,819 Number holding between 50 and 100 Acres: 45,394 Number holding between 100 and 200 Acres: 17,121 Number holding between 200 and 500 Acres: 6,393 Number holding between 500 and 1000 Acres: 1,179 Number holding between 1000 and 2000 Acres: 286 Number holding between 2000 and 3000 Acres: 46 Number holding between 3000 and 4000 Acres: 13 Number holding between 4000 and 5000 Acres: 3 N.B. - This Table is altered from one inserted in Captain Kennedy's most able Digest of Evidence on Occupation of Land in Ireland - a work which cannot be too carefully studied by all who would obtain a knowledge of the actual state of that unhappy country. |
||
This table
shows,
that of 974,000 agricultural families, only 40,000 are altogether
without land,
and that more than 500,000 occupy farms of eight acres or upwards.
Eight acres
are quite enough to enable a tenant family, paying a fair rent, to
obtain a competent
maintenance; so that occupiers of this class, in order to be enabled to
thrive,
require only a secure tenure, or, in other words, the security of
leases, with
such conditions as would ensure to them a fair remuneration for their
expenditure of money and labour. Without such leases, wherever the
cultivators
are not owners of the soil, it is impossible that agriculture can
flourish; and
wise landlords are as ready to grant as tenants are anxious to receive
them;
but landlords in general are short-sighted judges of their own
interests, and
with the view of quickening their perceptions, it has been proposed to
make
rent irrecoverable without a lease. The late Mr. O’Connell,
by whom this
expedient was recommended [10],
acknowledged it to be a violent remedy; but a more
serious objection is, that it would probably have little effect upon
the
disease. The value of leases depends entirely on their provisions; and
the
Legislature, although it might require them to be granted, could not
pretend to
regulate the demands for rent, or the other conditions to be imposed
upon the
tenants. Thus the only lease to which the landlord would consent, might
be such
as either the tenant would not accept, or such as would fetter without
protecting him. As a substitute for leases, the propriety of
establishing
tenant right throughout The waste land of the best quality is, however, far from being fit for immediate cultivation. Some of it may only require to be pared, burnt, and limed, but much is bog or moor, which requires to be thoroughly drained, and to have the sub-soil mixed with the surface mould and with lime; but these, and all other preliminary operations, might be performed at very little expense by the persons for whose ultimate benefit they were designed. The proposed grantees are at present without employment, and, unless some such measure as that under consideration be adopted, without any prospect of it. They are now, and they must continue for an indefinite period, to be supported at the public expense, and it would be much cheaper to keep them usefully engaged than to maintain them in idleness. It would therefore be good economy to take them forthwith into pay, and to employ them in draining and sub-soiling the wastes selected for reclamation. After the completion of these preparatory operations, the next step would be to mark off districts suitable for the settlement of collections of families, which would vary in size according as the colonies were intended to constitute separate village communities, or to be united to communities previously existing. Each district should be divided into lots corresponding in number to the number of settlers, and the latter should be further required to construct a cottage, according to an approved plan, on every lot. Every family should then be placed in possession of one of the cottage farms, and be made perpetual lessee, at a fixed rent, and on certain other conditions, which will be more particularly described hereafter; and having been furnished with tools and some farming stock, should be instructed that, after the next harvest, they would have to provide for their support by their own industry. It would be necessary, in the first place, to buy up the proprietary rights possessed by private persons over the waste lands required. Of the perfect competence of the Legislature to enforce the sale of such rights, there can be no question. An authority which compels individuals to part with their most valued property, on the slightest pretext of public convenience, and which permits railway projectors to throw down manor-houses, and to cut up favourite pleasure-grounds, need not scruple to insist upon the sale of boggy meadows, or upland pastures, with the view of curing the destitution and misery of an entire people. But upon this point it is the less necessary to dwell, as the right of Parliament to dispose of the wastes has been asserted in the most explicit terms by the first Minister of the Crown [11]. The compensation to be made to the proprietors would depend on the present produce of the land. The average value of this cannot at present exceed two shillings an acre, so that two pounds an acre, equal to twenty years’ purchase, would be a very liberal payment for the fee-simple. The expense of thorough drainage would scarcely reach 4l. an acre, and that of sub-soiling would not exceed 30s. A cottage, with its appurtenances, suitable to a farm of eight acres, might be built for 40l. [12]; and the farmer, on entering, might manage to get on without an advance of more than 20l. the whole outlay may, therefore, be stated as follows: Purchase
of 1,6000,000
acres, at 2l per acre
£3,200,000 Expense
of drainage
and sub-soiling, at 5l. 10s.
£8,800,000 Construction
of
200,000 cottages, at 40l each
£8,000,000 Advances to 200,000 cottiers of 20l each £4,000,000 TOTAL: £24,000,000 Now there is no land so poor
that it may not be rendered
fertile by artificial means. Its barrenness commonly arises from the
deficiency
of certain substances, which need only to be supplied in order
completely to
change its character. To procure the requisite ingredients might,
perhaps, be a
work of much time and labour, to pay for which might cost so much as to
make
the business anything but a profitable employment of money. But no such
objection could apply, if none but spare and superabundant labour were
used:
the work, however tedious and toilsome, would then cost absolutely
nothing. However
great the expenditure of labour, none of it would be wasted, for the
labour
would only have acquired value by being so expanded. No ground is so
worthless
that an English labourer will not eagerly accept an allotment of it for
the
occupation of his leisure, and that he will not speedily convert it
into a
productive garden, benefiting himself proportionably at the same time.
Nor is
it only unmarketable labour that may be profitably employed in this
manner. In
long occupied and well-peopled territories, where wages are not
extraordinarily
high, and where good land is not easily procurable, it would seem that
no soil
can be so bad that a labourer, to whom it is granted in full property,
will not
find it for his interest to cultivate it, even though by so doing he
should be
obliged to neglect other employment. No soil can be imagined more
unsuitable
for vegetation than the sand with which the These examples may serve to
show that there is no land not
absolutely incapable of cultivation, of which the produce, though it
may not yield
profit enough to satisfy a capitalist, will yet not yield some profit
– will not
somewhat exceed the expenses of cultivation. In the expenses of
cultivation is
included the cultivator’s subsistence; there is, therefore,
no land from which
the cultivator may not obtain a livelihood. It is true that the Flemish
process, just described, is somewhat tedious, and would be but ill
adapted to
cultivators who were entirely dependent for subsistence on the land
they were
reclaiming. It would by no means suit our Irish colonists, for
instance, who
might perish with hunger while their farms were producing only crops of
brushwood. But neither would the adoption of so slow a process be
requisite on
the better sort of Irish waste land, which bears no sort of resemblance
to the
sands of It will have been observed,
that potatoes form, as it were,
the basis of the farming just referred to. They seem to be thought the
only
crop on which man can subsist, that in this climate can be obtained
from newly
reclaimed land without the assistance of manure [15],
and to be, consequently, the
only provisions which pauper cultivators could raise during the first
year. But
after failing in two successive seasons, this crop can no longer be
safely
depended upon; and should the disease, by which it has been twice
destroyed, be
still continuing its ravages when the waste lands are prepared for
tillage, a
considerable alteration of plan will be necessary. The changes will be
a
subject for regret, inasmuch as it will occasion a considerable
increase of
expenditure; but, on the other hand, its effect will be to hasten, by a
year or
two, the process of improvement. One object of every scheme for the
benefit of It will here be proper to show, that the management of eight acres of land will not be too severe a task for those on whom it is to be imposed, viz., for a family of five persons, including only one male adult, and possessing, besides their land and their industry, no other capital than the small advance made to them for the purchase or indispensable implements and stock. The head of such a family would not be able to procure either a horse or a plough, and would be obliged to use a spade; but this, as every one may see, by comparing a field and a garden, is by far the more efficient instrument when time will allow of its being used; and the only question is, therefore, whether one man could spare time for the spade work annually required on a farm of eight acres. A more than ordinary share would be necessary on waste land, during the first year or two after its reclamation, but still not more than could be easily performed. ‘A good labourer can trench four perches (each perch being a square of five and a-half yards) in a day, or dig eight perches. It will take him thirty days to trench an acre, and sixteen to dig it well.’[16] If placed in possession of his farm in October, therefore, he could easily dig six acres before the season arrived for planting potatoes and sowing turnips; and when a regular rotation of crops was established, his labours would be greatly abridged. Suppose him to appropriate three more acres to corn, one to potatoes, one to clover, and one to turnips, and to keep two under grass. Between harvest and spring he must trench one acre twenty inches deep, and manure it for potatoes, and dig three acres; one acre being under clover, sown with the corn of the previous season, will not require digging, and another will have been sufficiently prepared for wheat by taking up of a former crop of potatoes. His spade work will occupy him only seventy-eight days, and he will have the rest of the year for wheeling manure, harrowing, sowing, planting, mowing, and reaping, while his wife and children weed the crops, tend to the cows and pigs, and perform other light offices. The whole amount of labour would be but a moderate burden for the united strength of the family, whose own fault alone it would be if they did not prosper. But it is not sufficient to have shown what a mine of wealth lies hidden in the waste land, if there be reason to believe that it would not be properly wrought by the settlers whom it is proposed to place there. A colony of Flemings, in such a situation, would speedily bring the soil to the highest pitch of fertility, and enrich themselves with the abundant tribute they would extort from it; but Irishmen, it will be said, are not Flemings [17]. The former would, indeed, have the same motives for industry. In their proprietary character, they would possess that strongest of all incentives to exertion, the knowledge that they were working for themselves; they would feel the influence of that affection for their little domains, which, according to Adam Smith, makes small proprietors ‘the most industrious, the most intelligent, and the most successful of improvers’ – of that ‘magic of property,’ which, as Arthur Young says, ‘turns sand to gold.’ Such impulses might be irresistible be ordinary mortals; but Irishmen are apparently considered exempt from the rules by which mankind in general are governed. It seems to be thought that with them self-interest is less powerful than habit; that having hitherto always lived in constrained inactivity, they now value no privilege so highly as idleness; that having never possessed anything but the merest necessaries of life, they have little desire for its comforts, or, at any rate, think them not worth the price of steady labour. What little employment is at present offered to them, either in their own potato grounds, or by larger occupiers, is often either neglected, or listlessly performed; and it may be suspected that they would exhibit the same apathy, even if constituted owners of farms large enough to furnish them with constant occupation, more especially when those farms, consisting of land recently reclaimed, demanded more than ordinary assiduity for the development of their resources. In reply to this, reference might be made to the notorious fact, that Irish labourers, when removed to situations in which industry is liberally rewarded, exert themselves as strenuously as those of any other nation; and even in Ireland examples are not wanting of peasants not only working hard, but applying themselves with ardour and success to the very occupation, their fitness for which we are now considering. Young observed, long ago, that ‘little occupiers who can get leases of a mountain side, make exertions in improvement, which, though far enough from being complete, show clearly what great effects encouragement would have amongst them;’ and he adds, ‘that the idleness seen among them when working for those who oppress them, is a very contrast to the vigour and activity with which the same people work, when themselves alone reap the benefit of their labour.’[18] Among the grounds for this estimate of the Irish character, was an experiment tried by Young himself. On Lord Kingsborough’s estate he marked a road, and assigned portions of the waste on each side to such as were willing to form the fences in the manner prescribed, to cultivate and inhabit the land, allowing each a guinea towards his cabin, and promising the best land rent free for three years, and the worst for five. The eagerness with which the poor people came into the scheme, convinced him that they wanted nothing but a little encouragement, to enter with all their might and spirit into the work of improvement. They trusted to his assurance to go to work upon the ditches, and actually made a considerable progress. ‘In all undertakings of this kind in Ireland,’ he continues, ‘it is the poor cottars and the very little farmers who are the best tools to employ, and the best tenants to let the land to;’[19] and this is confirmed by Mr Nicholls, who says that ‘most of the recently reclaimed land which he saw in the western counties, was reclaimed by the small occupiers, who drained and inclosed an acre or two at a time.’[20] But the evidence taken by the Land Commission, being the latest, may also be considered the most valuable. A practice, we are told, not uncommonly adopted by Irish farmers, is, that of ‘giving a small piece of waste land to a poor cottar or herdsman, for the first three crops, after which the improved portion is returned to the farmer, and a fresh portion is taken on the same terms by the cottar. Here are persons of the very poorest class obtaining a livelihood by the cultivation of waste land, under the most discouraging and least remunerative circumstances that can well be imagined.’ Where more favourable terms are conceded to the tenants, the progress of improvement is proportionate. On the Lough-ash estate, in Tyrone, about four hundred acres of waste land have been distributed among thirty tenants, most of whom have leases for twenty-one years, and obtained the land rent free for the first part of the term, on condition of paying a gradually increasing rent during the remainder. These tenants took possession of their respective allotments at different periods, between the years 1829 and 1840. They belonged originally to the ‘poorest classes of cottars;’ but when visited by the Land Commissioners, ‘had raised themselves into a comfortable body of farmers.’[21] Examples of this kind may not, however, be numerous enough to establish a national reputation for industry, and it would no doubt be safer to assume that the energies of the Irish peasantry would require to be artificially stimulated. Without adopting the theory of the incorrigible laziness of the Celtic race, with which some writers perversely choose to stultify all their own suggestions for the benefit of Ireland, we may acknowledge it to be doubtful whether people who had been dawdling about all their lives, would, when regular occupation were offered to them, spontaneously apply themselves to it. There is certainly some reason to apprehend, that if settlers of this description were merely translated to their respective allotments, and there abandoned to their own devices, many of them might prefer sloth and poverty to toil and comfort; and, at any rate, no appeal to their hopes or fears, that might help to rouse them to activity, should be rejected as superfluous. Some direct attempts might be made to imbue them with new and improved tastes, and they should certainly be made acquainted with the advantages of their position, taught how to avail themselves of them, and threatened with their withdrawal in the event of their neglecting to make use of them. One advantage of having the houses on the reclaimed lands built under the superintendence of public officers, would be, that their occupants would receive at once tolerably exalted notions of one sort of comfort, of which they might long have remained ignorant, if they had been permitted to build dwellings according to their own fancy, and had taken for their models the vile styes from which they had previously been satisfied. In general, however, it is sufficient, in order to create new wants, that the means of gratifying them be provided. If the colonists could be made to understand, that by taking a little pains they could procure good clothes and good food, they would quickly discover that a whole coat is better than rags, and that a dinner of potatoes would be immensely improved by the addition of bread and cheese and bacon. In order to convey to them the needful preliminary information, the whole number of colonies might be arranged in districts, to each of which should be appointed a scientific agriculturist, whose duty it would be to visit periodically every farm place under his superintendence, and to instruct the owner in the principles of husbandry. Such agricultural teachers are already employed by several landlords, and have in general done much good. When their advice has not been neutralised by superciliousness on their part, it has commonly been very well received. They have easily overcome the prejudices against new practices, entertained by the peasantry, and have persuaded them to adopt improved modes of drainage, better rotations, artificial grasses, and green crops.[22] Equal success might be expected with the settlers on the waste lands, and the more surely, as with regard to them, a little compulsion might be used in case of need. The permanence of their tenure might be declared contingent on their behaviour, and they might be threatened with the resumption of their grants unless their farms were brought into cultivation within a specified time. Such measures, however, would be necessary only with the original colonists, whose vicious habits, inherited from a long line of ancestors, might frustrate any scheme that depended for success on their eradication. But the second and all succeeding generations might be trained betimes in the way in which they should walk. The influence of education might be brought to bear upon them by machinery to be provided in the following manner. The home colonies would either be annexed to villages previously existing, or would constitute distinct communities; and on account of the situation of the waste lands, the latter arrangement would probably be by far the most general. To each of the separate colonies should be appointed a schoolmaster, who besides the usual qualifications for the post, should be required to have studied at an agricultural seminary, and thus to have become competent to impart to the children of farmers the special instruction which such pupils require. Every householder should be required by the conditions of his tenure to send his children, between certain ages, to attend the lessons of this master, whose remuneration should consist partly of a fee for every pupil, partly of a rent-free house and ground, and party of a rent charge on the land. In a community consisting at first of two hundred families, and occupying consequently sixteen hundred acres, a contribution of eighteen-pence an acre would amount to 120l a year, which, added to the other emoluments of the office, would procure the services of a properly qualified person. The spiritual instruction of the community might be provided for in a similar manner by the appointment of a priest, who, besides a manse and glebe, and the usual ecclesiastical fees, should be allowed a stipend of the same amount as the schoolmaster, and arising from the same source. The rate which it would be necessary to levy for the payment of both religious and secular teachers, and for the satisfaction of the government claim, would not exceed twelve shillings an acre, or only one-third of the rent that might readily be obtained for the land. With these precautions, there
can be little doubt that the experiment
would succeed. The wastes recommended for reclamation are such as would
deserve
the attention even of a speculator, seeking, not a mere livelihood, but
a
profitable investment for his money; for experience has shown that an
outlay of
five or six pounds per acre would add twenty or thirty shillings to the
rentable
value. Six acres of such land, held at the full rent, enable the
Belgian
tenant-farmer, not only to live in comfort, but to save money. Eight
acres,
therefore, held in perpetuity at a rent of only one-third the original
yearly
value, could not be an inadequate provision even for Irishmen, if only
the
latter could be induced to work; and it is proposed to urge them to
exertion by every
motive that can stimulate industry.
Perhaps then we may be permitted to assume that the original grantees
would
rise from their present indigence to comparative affluence. It remains
to be
considered whether their prosperity would be permanent or whether it
would be
frittered away by the gradual subdivision of the original tenements.
The
question of the inherent tendency of small properties to continual
diminution
has already been fully discussed, and it is hoped that sufficient cause
has
been shown for answering it in the negative. The partition of land, it
appears,
is seldom carried too far except where the various claimants have, by
constant
companionship with privation, learned to expect nothing more than a
bare
subsistence, and have no means of obtaining even that except from the
occupation
of a piece of ground; and it is probable, that even Irishmen, when
relieved
from the necessity which now leaves them no alternative but to divide
the
holdings of their parents, would refrain from a course of which they
could not
fail to perceive the ruinous consequences. With all their Irishism,
they are
not altogether void of reason, but would probably act in much the same
manner
as other rational beings in similar circumstances. If brought up in the
enjoyment of competence, they would not content themselves with a mere
pittance, merely because they could derive it from land of their own.
If their
patrimony were insufficient to maintain them in the style to which they
had
been accustomed, they would rather dispose of it and seek a livelihood
elsewhere. Such are natural inferences from observation of what happens
among
peasant proprietors in other countries. Still, if attention be confined
to When it was proposed to divide
the reclaimed wastes into
allotments of eight acres, it was not intended to attach any special
importance
to that size, or to recommend that it should be protected against
subsequent
alteration. There is, however, a minimum size which properties must
possess in
order to deserve the name of farms, and a maximum size which they
cannot exceed
without ceasing to be peasant properties. These limits cannot be
defined, for
they differ in different situations with the productiveness of the
soil, and the
skill and industry of the cultivator; but we will suppose that in
Ireland,
under good management, five acres would furnish a family with full
occupation and
plentiful subsistence, and that fifty acres would elevate the owner
above the
condition of a mere husbandman. If it should be thought desirable to
prescribe
these as the most usual boundaries for the possessions of the settlers
and
their descendants, without, however, absolutely prohibiting the future
formation of any of larger or smaller size – the end might be
attained by some
rules as the following. An owner of more than five acres might be
allowed the power
of alienation during his lifetime, provided that he did not dispose of
a
smaller portion than five acres. A person whose estate did not reach
that limit
should not be permitted to diminish it, but if desirous of alienating,
should
be required to alienate the whole. Every landowner having children
might be
allowed to select from amongst them one or more to be his heirs,
provided that
he bequeathed to no one more than fifty acres, without making the same
provision
for as many of his other children as his estate would permit; and
provided
also, that he bequeathed to none a portion of less than five acres,
unless,
after division into portions of five acres, one portion of inferior
extent
should remain, of which he might then be permitted to make a separate
bequest.
In the case of persons dying intestate, the eldest son should, if the
estate
were under five acres, be entitled to the whole, and if it exceeded
that limit,
should take the principal dwelling-house and five acres adjoining. The
remainder of the land might be distributed among the other children or
among as
many of them in order of seniority as could put in possession of five
acres
each. If any land then remained, it might, if less than five acres, be
given to
the eldest of the children previously unprovided for; and if it
exceeded five
acres, it should be divided equally among all the children, care being
taken in
such partitions that every inheritance should be compact, and not
composed of
scattered fragments. It will no doubt be perceived that a law of
succession
like this, though professedly designed to prevent the size from falling
below
five acres, would not only permit, but would favour, the formation of
some
properties of smaller size. It must also be remarked, however, that it
would
limit the number of such properties; and would moreover prevent a
property of
less than five acres, when once formed, from being again subdivided.
With these
precautions, the existence of such properties, instead of being an
evil, would
be attended with the best consequences. If there were no farms too
large to be
cultivated exclusively by the occupiers, pieces of land too small to
furnish
their owners with adequate employment and subsistence, might be
productive of
idleness and poverty, for the deficiency of their resources could not
be
supplied. But in Thus, in the colonisation of the waste lands is offered a means of speedily raising the most destitute portion of the Irish people to independence and comfort, and of permanently securing those blessings to their descendents. But the advantages of the scheme would not be confined to those most directly affected by it, but would be shared largely by the remainder of the peasantry, and more or less by every section of the nation. By the removal of nearly two hundred thousand families from the lands already cultivated, an end would be put to the ruinous competition in the land and labour markets; labour would command, and land would be obtainable at reasonable prices; rent would fall to the amount which the farmer could pay without impoverishing himself, and wages would rise in consequence, both of the decrease in the number of labourers, and of the increase of the means of the farmers. Improvement to this extent would take place naturally and as a necessary consequence of the reclamation of the waste lands, and legislative interference would be requisite only to promote and confirm it. With these views, two suggestions may be offered: one, the enactment of a law rendering the grant of leases obligatory, a measure which, if no longer recommended by the same urgent necessity, would, when tenants were able to negotiate with landlords on more equal terms, be no longer open to the same objection as at present; and the other, the allotment to the labourers remaining on the present cultivated area, of plots of common land, of half an acre or an acre in extent, on the same conditions as the grants made to the settlers on the wastes. The whole body of peasantry – labourers, cottars, and farmers – would then, for the first time, be placed in situations in which their subsequent lot would depend upon their own exertions. Specific instruction might still be necessary to teach them the value of the means at their command, but were this afforded, it cannot be doubted that industry would require no other stimulus than self-interest. Industry would introduce plenty, and plenty be accompanied by content. Tranquillity would succeed to desperation and violence, and capital would no longer be deterred from flowing wherever a suitable field were offered for its employment. Canals and railways would at once mark and facilitate the progress of enterprise, mines would be worked, fisheries and such manufactures as were adapted to the country established, the conveniences of civilised life would be multiplied and brought within the reach of every class of the community. The advance of national prosperity would correspond with that of individual happiness. The whole empire would receive a vast accession of vigour when its most exhausting drain was converted into an abundant source of wealth, and when the festering wound in one of her principal members was at length healed. |
||
[1]
Pomp. Mela,
de Situ Orbis, lib. iii. eap. 6. [2] 'Gens agriculturae labores aspernans, a primo pastorali vivendi modo non recedens.' - Giraldus Cambrensis apud Moore, Hist. of Ireland, vol. i. p. 317 [3] Moore, vol. i. p. 191 [4] Spenser's View of Ireland, Dublin, 1763, p.230. [5] Johnes's Froissart, Edition of 1839, vol. ii. p 578 [6] Spenser. View of Ireland, pp. 125-7. [7] Young's Tour in Ireland, vol. ii. App. pp. 25 -7. [8] In the north of Ireland, Arthur Young in 1776, found that ten acres were considered a large farm, and five or six a good one (Tour, vol. ii. App. p. 21). Farms had been reduced to that size because the tenants, being rather weavers than farmers, required no more land to furnish them with a competent livelihood; but having once reached that limit, they did not afterwards fall below it, being at this day quite as large as they were seventy years ago. [9] This is the proportion of land to male adult labourers; but of agricultural labourers of both sexes and of all ages, there is one for every twenty-four acres, as stated at p.8. [10] Arthur Young had long before suggested, as a necessary step towards improvement, that 'the meanest occupier should have a lease, and none shorter than twenty-one years.' (Tour, vol. ii. App. p. 24). [11] Lord J. Russell's Speech on the State of Ireland, Jan. 25th, 1847 [12] Digest of Evidence on Occ. of Land, pp. 82-3 and p 139 [13] Upon mountain wastes, as all wastes in Ireland, that are not bog, are called, 'is to be practised,' says Young, 'the most profitable husbandry in the king's dominions, for so I am persuaded the improvement of mountain land to be.' (Tour, vol. ii. App. p. 69.) And again, 'no meadows are equal to those gained by improving a bog; they are of a value which scarcely any other lands give rise to. In Ireland, I should suppose, it would not fall short of forty shillings an acre, and rise in many cases to three pounds.' (Ibid. p. 74). [14] Flemish Husbandry, pp. 11 - 13 [15] Young, however, from land which had been merely pared, burnt, and limed, took crops of wheat, rye, and bere, the first year. (Tour, vol. ii. App. p. 70.) [16] Flemish Husbandry, p. 75 [17] Young has some remarks so singularly apposite, that it would be unpardonable not to insert them here. 'A few considerable landlords,' he says, 'many years ago, made the experiment of fixing, at great expense, colonise of Palatines on their estates. They had houses built for them, plots of land assigned to each, at a rent of favour, assisted in stock, and all of them with leases for lives from the head landlord. The poor Irish are very rarely treated in this manner, but when they are, they work much greater improvements than are common among these Germans.' (Tour in Ireland, vol. ii. App. pp.24, 25). [18] Tour, vol. ii. App. pp. 22 and 72. [19] Tour, vol ii. App. p. 72. [20] Nicholls's Reports on Irish Poor Laws, p. 18. [21] Digest of Evidence on Occupation of Land, p.570. [22] Digest of Evidence, ut supra, p. 28. |